|
The
Growing Crisis in Public Higher Education
Sylvia Manning, chancellor of the University
of Illinois at Chicago,
gave this address at the Illinois AAUP’s 2004 Annual Meeting
in Chicago.
I was asked to speak
on any topic of my choosing—so long as it was related to the
conference theme of Contingent Faculty. What I would like to do
is to set the topic of contingent faculty in a wider context, and
then return to some of the consequences as I see them. In the process,
it is probable that I will say some things that some people here
will find offensive. But among my privileges as chancellor is to
serve the campus on which Stanley Fish resides (and presides) as
dean of the College of Liberal Arts and Sciences. I have learned
much from Stanley, including to offend honestly and without rancor,
and not to swerve from the logic of my position for fear of giving
offense.
The wider topic
is the entire issue of public higher education. Let me begin with
some data from the January, 2004 issue of Postsecondary Education
Opportunity, prepared by Thomas G. Mortenson at the Pell Institute
for the Study of Opportunity in Higher Education. Mortenson and
his associates charted the change in state tax fund appropriations
per $1000 of state personal income between fiscal years 1978 and
2004. In 49 states, that change is a decline, from one half of one
percent in Kentucky to 67.5% in Colorado. The one exception is New
Mexico, which shows a gain of a whopping 0.2%. When they tracked
the change over only three years, between fiscal years 2001 and
2004, five states showed positive, from 1.1% in South Dakota to
29.5% in Nevada; the rest are negative, up to negative 36.9% in
Massachusetts. Based on these trends, they then calculated the
dates by which, if circumstances don’t change, the state tax
appropriations to higher education will reach zero. There are different
dates for different states, as one would expect, with the first
being Alaska in 2019 and the average, so to speak, being 2053. Right
now, the University of California is talking about cutting back
enrollment, and in Colorado the legislature is thinking about zeroing
out the state appropriation to higher education right now and replacing
it with a voucher system—something that is actually looking
good to many in the universities. To indulge our natural provincialism,
one might ask where Illinois stands in these numbers. In the decline
in state tax fund appropriations per $1000 of state personal income
between fiscal years 1978 and 2004, Illinois ranks #18 (from least
to greatest decline), at 28.2%. Between fiscal years 2001 and 2004,
Illinois ranks #27, at 11.3%. We can expect to reach zero in 2093.
By that time I will have been chancellor for 95 years, but I worry
nonetheless. I have two additional measures for Illinois that
may be of interest to you. According to the Illinois Economic and
Fiscal Commission, July 2003, in per capita state and local government
expenditures for higher education in 2000, Illinois ranked 41st.
Thus while the Mortenson analysis puts us about in the middle of
the states, the EFC approach puts us far lower. The other measure
is simply to chart state tax appropriations to higher education
in Illinois in constant dollars since FY1990. In that 14-year period,
it can be argued that higher education funding about tracked the
CPI. But if you look at it by sector, you see that funding for the
retirement system increased 126% as the state attempted to address
the deficit created by prior years’ failure to fund the program;
student assistance commission (ISAC) funding increased by 42%; while
community college funding declined by almost 8% and public university
funding declined by almost 12%. The latter represent the operating
budgets of the institutions. What we see here is a precipitous
and, I would argue, not thought out, retreat from the fundamental
commitment to public higher education that has been part of public
policy in this country since the Morrill Act. A century of progress,
gradual, fitful, but ultimately powerful, in being reversed. The
Morrill Act, for all its recognition of the liberal arts, had its
focus upon agriculture and the mechanical and industrial arts, later
to be spoken of as engineering. Our development of public higher
education, education within reach of the children of farmers and
laborers, followed the shift in the economic base of the country
from agrarian to industrial while it recognized as well the importance
of higher education to a democratic citizenry. In the post-Sputnik
era, our cold war fears drove a significant spike in spending on
higher education. Has anything changed to make higher education
less important, less critical to the sustenance of democracy or
simply to our economic well-being? Obviously not. Few would disagree
with the proposition to the contrary, that higher education continues
to grow more important, more critical, more fundamental to our prospects
for comfort, let alone prosperity. Even those who see long-range
good in that current object of media hype, the outsourcing of white-collar,
service industries to countries like China and India, put their
faith in the new, still knowledge-based jobs to come. But what if
we lose not only our technological leadership, but our supply of
workers educated or educable for those jobs?
We see this
condition looming in the sciences, and likely to be exacerbated
by the recent dramatic decline in graduate-school applications from
foreign students, propelled by the difficulties of obtaining visas
and the perception that the U.S. is no longer a friendly host. We
simply do not have in the U.S. the high school graduates to lead
to the college graduates who can run our laboratories. We also see
universities, strapped for resources, raising fees for foreign students,
to the point where they become less competitive for the ablest of
those students. One may understand the argument that taxpayer resources
should not subsidize the education of non-residents, but the brute
fact is that we need their brain-power. At the same time that we
are cutting back on our preparation of domestic students, political
and financial circumstances are leading us to choke off the supply
of foreign students. Let me honor my humanist background by
closing this segment of my argument with some reference to the non-economic
and non-technological importance of a wider and better, not narrower
and leaner, higher education for Americans. Democracy is always
fragile, and ours is not at a particularly strong point. We are
torn by ideological strife and by the inequities of our society,
especially as those inequities parallel ethnic and racial difference.
While higher education is no guarantor of mutual understanding,
tolerance, or peaceful coexistence, it seems to go further towards
those ends, in an irreversibly multicultural society, than anything
else we know or have. Certainly we have evidence that higher
education has significant effect upon lifetime earnings, and earnings,
in the United States, are the markers of class. There is in reality
no such thing as equal opportunity without equal access to education,
be that education technological, scientific, artistic, humanist,
or professional. If access to higher education diminishes, class
stratification increases. Nothing I have said is original. These
things are known, and known widely. Why, then, has the decline in
state support for higher education happened, what are its likely
consequences, and what ought we to do about it?
The recent
recession has focused us upon issues of revenue. But from what I
read, it seems that in the longer term the problem will not be revenue;
it will be expense. Illinois, at present, is trapped in a vise created
by a governor committed not to raise the state’s flat, unprogressive,
3% personal income tax, yet faced with a multi-billion-dollar shortfall.
For many of us, myself included, the middle-term solution is to
raise taxes. The stinker is that whereas an increase in taxes—even
the suggestion of an increase—will be felt immediately, it
will take some years before the effects of the current cutbacks
to higher education will be apparent. And legislators generally
respond to the immediate effects. But I’m not sure that
a tax increase alone would do it in the longer term. State budgets
are being pressed by rising health care costs, and as the population
ages and lives longer, will be even more pressed. The federal budget
will reel under social security unless major reforms are enacted,
and pension plans at other levels may have similar problems. States
don’t have the money, health care costs grow and seem unavoidable,
K-12 is sacrosanct (and should be): what’s left, other than
higher education? And higher education has, seemingly, another option:
it can raise tuition. And we have raised tuition, dramatically,
across the country. Now I happen to be a firm believer in a high-tuition/high-aid
approach. If the government cannot afford to provide a quality education
at low price for all, then in order to sustain quality those who
can afford it should pay more, and those who cannot should not.
The way to get to that condition is to set a high tuition price
and then discount based on need (and need only, not so-called merit).
To some extent, therefore, I am an advocate of raising tuition prices—so
long as financial aid is raised commensurately. So far, we have
done that at the University of Illinois. It is not clear that we
can continue to do that much more, if only because at some point
we reach the limit in the top price. And even so, we have only partly
offset the state cuts. So what happens then? One of two things,
or some uneasy mixture of both. One, the public universities price
themselves out of reach of the lower-income students, failing to
provide adequate financial aid to offset the higher prices. Alternatively,
the public universities keep their tuition down and allow the quality
of the education they offer to decline. Either way, what then evolves
is a two-tiered system of higher education, one for the well-to-do
and a lesser, poorer one for the not-well-to-do—and for some
of the latter, none. Some will argue that the solution is for
public universities to become more efficient, to eliminate waste,
cut down bureaucracy, etc. We have been doing that, arguably for
25 years, except where federal and state legal requirements forced
us in the other direction. And if we haven’t yet found every
possible saving, at some point we will have done so. For most of
us, cuts have already reached the core mission. We can be leaner,
but our best faculty and staff will migrate to the less lean. It
has already become, in some quarters, a recruiting field-day for
the better-off private institutions. It is not only that a two-tiered
system of higher education based upon family wealth is inequitable;
it is also that it is not in the public interest. By failing to
provide first-quality opportunity to all our children, we fail to
mine all the talent we have. For quality of life, for economic competitiveness,
for justice and health, we need all that talent. Those who are denied
opportunity are not the only ones who suffer: the entire society
loses the benefit of their development as members of that society.
Now, let’s get to contingent faculty. I want to say a few
things. One should be obvious by now: I believe that the rise of
contingent faculty—excepting always those professionals who
teach part-time by choice and who bring the special value of their
professional lives to the classroom—has been neither more
nor less than one outcome of the financial squeeze on higher education.
I recognize that not everyone here today works at a public university.
But public universities, nationwide, drive the statistics: almost
80% of students are in public institutions, and probably a similar
percentage of faculty. And in Illinois, and some other states as
well, the cutback in state tax-based support of higher education
has affected private institutions as well, if only through the student
financial aid program. Because contingent faculty are not eligible
for tenure, and because they participate much less, often not at
all, in university governance, their employment in large numbers
negatively affects not only their lives, but the institutions that
employ them. Joe Berry’s lead article in the Spring 2004 issue
of Illinois Academe describes these effects in detail, and I won’t
repeat them. Basically, the employment of large numbers of contingent
faculty saves money—and does nothing else that is good, and
a number of things that are bad for students and bad for the institutions.
On the matter of governance, however, I do want to quote Mr. Berry.
He writes, “An even more insidious impact is the collective
disempowerment of the faculty as a whole. With the majority now
contingent, the power of faculty to impact administrative decisions
is greatly reduced.” I agree with that statement, though it
may make a difference to some that I am concerned about what it
says less as a matter of faculty power per se than as a matter of
good governance. That is, I don’t think a university reaches
good decisions without a lot of strong faculty input, and even when
it reaches good decisions, it can’t implement them without
preferably enthusiastic, and at any rate willing, faculty cooperation.
But then Mr. Berry writes two further sentences: “That is
not accidental. It is part of a conscious administrative strategy
with the abolition of tenure as a major part.” Those two sentences—and
don’t say I didn’t keep my promise to offend—are
nonsense. Unlike most of the other statements in the essay, they
are offered without any evidence, and I suspect there’s good
reason for that. That the growth of contingent faculty results
in the weakening of tenure must be true, at least at some undetermined
tipping-point in that growth. But that there exists some administrative
strategy to destroy tenure, either among a smaller group of unnamed
administrators at unnamed institutions, or uniformly nationwide,
or in some Platonic meta-reality, is a ridiculous and, I would submit,
dangerous proposition. Let me say why. First, it is useful to
keep in mind that those administrators who make the critical decisions,
including the decision to hire contingent and part-time rather than
tenure-track and full-time faculty, come, at about 98%, from faculty
ranks. (I must confess: I made that number up, but I’d bet
on it.)
I have always
been bemused by the apparent belief that as these people move from
their full-time faculty positions into administrative roles, a profound
change in their values takes place. People have various ideas as
to which administrators make those decisions. At the lowest level,
it’s the department head or chair. I’ve never met one
who wouldn’t rather get a tenure-line from the dean than some
one-year or one-semester cash. The same goes for the dean’s
preference with regard to the provost. And it is usually the provost
who is stuck having the balance the checkbook. Certainly there
is pressure upon presidents and provosts to balance that checkbook.
Usually, in fact, there is no possibility of imbalance. Contingent
faculty, I would argue from what experience and knowledge I have,
is a contingent decision, forced by unpleasant circumstances.
Do the provosts and presidents want to satisfy those who require
the balanced budgets? Certainly. Can they lose their jobs if they
don’t deliver balanced budgets? Often. But is that their highest
aspiration? Rarely. How do we know what their highest aspiration
is? I’d suggest, by listening to what they brag about. They
don’t brag about their balanced budgets, and they brag about
their cost-savings only to audiences that require cost-savings as
a condition of further funding. They do brag, incessantly, about
the quality of their institutions. The quality of true higher education
depends upon academic freedom, and the safeguard for academic freedom
is tenure. You might wonder why I am going on about this. It
is because the belief that there is a malevolent force at work here
against the contingent faculty is part of a stance that can do us
yet more harm. Higher education, and especially public higher education,
is up against some formidable forces. In various quarters we face
postures of hostility bred of political opportunism, genuine hostility,
enormous competing social needs, indifference, suspicion as to both
our motives and our competence. We face these things together. We
may see ourselves in numerous parts—faculty, staff, administration
and students; or scientists, humanists, artists and health professionals—but
most of the world sees us as monolith: universities. I’ll
get back to this point in a minute. First, I want to give a
bit more time to the question of what we should be doing. It has
become fairly common wisdom that we in public higher education must
“privatize.” To privatize apparently means to start
acting more like private institutions, to be less dependent on state
government funding. The question is, which private institutions
should we, and could we, be more like? I would like UIC to be more
like Harvard. If you’re old-time Chicago you may recall the
moniker for Navy Pier of “Harvard on the Rocks.” I’d
like to just drop the Rocks. But I’ll compromise: we’d
only be a bit like Harvard, just the bit that would trade off our
state tax revenues for endowment income revenues. UIC has been
getting about $300 million from the state. To get endowment income
of $300 million, you need an endowment of about $6 billion. Yes,
philanthropy has a role to play, but it isn’t going to replace
lost state revenues any time soon. Harvard recently announced with
pride that it would no longer charge tuition to students from families
earning less than $40,000. That’s admirable and enviable.
But at UIC, it is already the case that 34% of our undergraduates
receive Pell grants and about 35% receive Illinois MAP awards. I
found myself wondering what percent of Harvard undergraduates actually
come from families with incomes under $40,000. We could also
privatize by raising tuition as high as the market would bear. For
our student demographic, we would also have to raise financial aid
at a somewhat faster rate than we raised tuition, if we were going
to sustain access. Or we could privatize in the sense that we could
decide that full access is someone else’s problem. Access
has been the problem—and the privilege—of the publics,
but if the publics privatize, whose will it be?
There are other things we can do, and most we will do. We will seek
more philanthropic assistance, and invest in doing so. We will raise
tuition somewhat. We will encourage the patenting and licensing
of our intellectual property that has commercial potential, in the
hope of payoffs that can support our mission, of which advanced
research is a major part. We will pursue greater administrative
efficiency, trying at the same time not to cut the services that
make our environment attractive to faculty and students. We may
even figure out how to make more money through self-sustaining continuing
education enterprises. But at the end of the day, I believe
that if we cannot recapture the public confidence in what we do
and the public commitment to the social value of what we do, we
will not be able to sustain our mission of access to quality education.
And I also believe that we will not succeed in that recapture if
we do not act together. Against the array of circumstances and forces
threatening the very nature of our mutual enterprise, our only hope
is to stand together. We need all our collective resources. If we
are divided, we will be conquered. And that is why I said a
few minutes ago that Mr. Berry’s hypothesis of an adverse
administrative intention is dangerous. In some dimensions, the structure
of universities puts administration and contingent faculty in a
relationship of conflict. I have $10,000 and I need to cover two
courses and so I want to hire two people at $5,000. The two people
want $6,000 each and probably both need and deserve it. Now what?
I’m not
going to try to answer that, at least today. But if the answer drives
us into opposing camps, if the opposition created on this particular
issue becomes generalized, so that we no longer see ourselves as
fighting essentially on the same side of the larger issue, then
it won’t matter who wins the battle between us, because together
we will lose the enterprise itself. We need to work together
not only to ameliorate the employment conditions of contingent faculty
and to return the large preponderance of faculty positions to regular,
tenure-track positions, but to preserve that fundamental nature
of our institutions that draws us to work for them. Thank you
for listening.
______________________
I am grateful to W. Randall Kangas, Assistant Vice President, University
of Illinois, for assistance with most of the numbers in this paper.
|
|