|
IL-AAUP
Meeting - April 17, 2004
Keynote Speaker - Dr. Sylvia Manning
Chancellor of the University of Illinois at Chicago
Good morning
and thank you for inviting me here today: it is an honor, and I
am flattered.
I was asked
to speak on any topic of my choosing—so long as it was related
to the conference theme of Contingent Faculty. What I would like
to do is to set the topic of contingent faculty in a wider context,
and then return to some of the consequences as I see them. In the
process, it is probable that I will say some things that some people
here will find offensive. But among my privileges as chancellor
is to serve the campus on which Stanley Fish resides (and presides)
as dean of the College of Liberal Arts and Sciences. I have learned
much from Stanley, including to offend honestly and without rancor,
and not to swerve from the logic of my position for fear of giving
offense.
The wider topic
is the entire issue of public higher education. Let me begin with
some data from the January, 2004 issue of Postsecondary Education
Opportunity, prepared by Thomas G. Mortenson at the Pell Institute
for the Study of Opportunity in Higher Education. Mortenson and
his associates charted the change in state tax fund appropriations
per $1000 of state personal income between fiscal years 1978 and
2004. In 49 states, that change is a decline, from one half of one
percent in Kentucky to 67.5% in Colorado. The one exception is New
Mexico, which shows a gain of a whopping 0.2%. When they tracked
the change over only three years, between fiscal years 2001 and
2004, five states showed positive, from 1.1% in South Dakota to
29.5% in Nevada; the rest are negative, up to negative 36.9% in
Massachusetts.
Based on these
trends, they then calculated the dates by which, if circumstances
don’t change, the state tax appropriations to higher education
will reach zero. There are different dates for different states,
as one would expect, with the first being Alaska in 2019 and the
average, so to speak, being 2053. Right now, the University of California
is talking about cutting back enrollment, and in Colorado the legislature
is thinking about zeroing out the state appropriation to higher
education right now and replacing it with a voucher system—something
that is actually looking good to many in the universities.
To indulge
our natural provincialism, one might ask where Illinois stands in
these numbers. In the decline in state tax fund appropriations per
$1000 of state personal income between fiscal years 1978 and 2004,
Illinois ranks #18 (from least to greatest decline), at 28.2%. Between
fiscal years 2001 and 2004, Illinois ranks #27, at 11.3%. We can
expect to reach zero in 2093. By that time I will have been chancellor
for 95 years, but I worry nonetheless.
I have two
additional measures for Illinois that may be of interest to you.
According to the Illinois Economic and Fiscal Commission, July 2003,
in per capita state and local government expenditures for higher
education in 2000, Illinois ranked 41st. Thus while the Mortenson
analysis puts us about in the middle of the states, the EFC approach
puts us far lower. The other measure is simply to chart state tax
appropriations to higher education in Illinois in constant dollars
since FY1990. In that fourteen-year period, it can be argued that
higher education funding about tracked the CPI. But if you look
at it by sector, you see that funding for the retirement system
increased 126% as the state attempted to address the deficit created
by prior years’ failure to fund the program; student assistance
commission (ISAC) funding increased by 42%; while community college
funding declined by almost 8% and public university funding declined
by almost 12%. The latter represent the operating budgets of the
institutions.
What we see
here is a precipitous and, I would argue, not thought out, retreat
from the fundamental commitment to public higher education that
has been part of public policy in this country since the Morrill
Act. A century of progress, gradual, fitful, but ultimately powerful,
in being reversed. The Morrill Act, for all its recognition of the
liberal arts, had its focus upon agriculture and the mechanical
and industrial arts, later to be spoken of as engineering. Our development
of public higher education, education within reach of the children
of farmers and laborers, followed the shift in the economic base
of the country from agrarian to industrial while it recognized as
well the importance of higher education to a democratic citizenry.
In the post-Sputnik era, our cold war fears drove a significant
spike in spending on higher education.
Has anything
changed to make higher education less important, less critical to
the sustenance of democracy or simply to our economic well-being?
Obviously not. Few would disagree with the proposition to the contrary,
that higher education continues to grow more important, more critical,
more fundamental to our prospects for comfort, let alone prosperity.
Even those who see long-range good in that current object of media
hype, the outsourcing of white-collar, service industries to countries
like China and India, put their faith in the new, still knowledge-based
jobs to come. But what if we lose not only our technological leadership,
but our supply of workers educated or educable for those jobs?
We see this
condition looming in the sciences, and likely to be exacerbated
by the recent dramatic decline in graduate-school applications from
foreign students, propelled by the difficulties of obtaining visas
and the perception that the U.S. is no longer a friendly host. We
simply do not have in the U.S. the high school graduates to lead
to the college graduates who can run our laboratories. We also see
universities, strapped for resources, raising fees for foreign students,
to the point where they become less competitive for the ablest of
those students. One may understand the argument that taxpayer resources
should not subsidize the education of non-residents, but the brute
fact is that we need their brain-power. At the same time that we
are cutting back on our preparation of domestic students, political
and financial circumstances are leading us to choke off the supply
of foreign students.
Let me honor
my humanist background by closing this segment of my argument with
some reference to the non-economic and non-technological importance
of a wider and better, not narrower and leaner, higher education
for Americans. Democracy is always fragile, and ours is not at a
particularly strong point. We are torn by ideological strife and
by the inequities of our society, especially as those inequities
parallel ethnic and racial difference. While higher education is
no guarantor of mutual understanding, tolerance, or peaceful coexistence,
it seems to go further towards those ends, in an irreversibly multicultural
society, than anything else we know or have.
Certainly we
have evidence that higher education has significant effect upon
lifetime earnings, and earnings, in the United States, are the markers
of class. There is in reality no such thing as equal opportunity
without equal access to education, be that education technological,
scientific, artistic, humanist, or professional. If access to higher
education diminishes, class stratification increases.
Nothing I have
said is original. These things are known, and known widely. Why,
then, has the decline in state support for higher education happened,
what are its likely consequences, and what ought we to do about
it?
The recent recession
has focused us upon issues of revenue. But from what I read, it
seems that in the longer term the problem will not be revenue; it
will be expense. Illinois, at present, is trapped in a vise created
by a governor committed not to raise the state’s flat, unprogressive,
3% personal income tax, yet faced with a multi-billion-dollar shortfall.
For many of us, myself included, the middle-term solution is to
raise taxes. The stinker is that whereas an increase in taxes—even
the suggestion of an increase—will be felt immediately, it
will take some years before the effects of the current cutbacks
to higher education will be apparent. And legislators generally
respond to the immediate effects.
But I’m
not sure that a tax increase alone would do it in the longer term.
State budgets are being pressed by rising health care costs, and
as the population ages and lives longer, will be even more pressed.
The federal budget will reel under social security unless major
reforms are enacted, and pension plans at other levels may have
similar problems. States don’t have the money, health care
costs grow and seem unavoidable, K-12 is sacrosanct (and should
be): what’s left, other than higher education? And higher
education has, seemingly, another option: it can raise tuition.
And we have
raised tuition, dramatically, across the country. Now I happen to
be a firm believer in a high-tuition/high-aid approach. If the government
cannot afford to provide a quality education at low price for all,
then in order to sustain quality those who can afford it should
pay more, and those who cannot should not. The way to get to that
condition is to set a high tuition price and then discount based
on need (and need only, not so-called merit). To some extent, therefore,
I am an advocate of raising tuition prices—so long as financial
aid is raised commensurately. So far, we have done that at the University
of Illinois. It is not clear that we can continue to do that much
more, if only because at some point we reach the limit in the top
price. And even so, we have only partly offset the state cuts.
So what happens
then? One of two things, or some uneasy mixture of both. One, the
public universities price themselves out of reach of the lower-income
students, failing to provide adequate financial aid to offset the
higher prices. Alternatively, the public universities keep their
tuition down and allow the quality of the education they offer to
decline. Either way, what then evolves is a two-tiered system of
higher education, one for the well-to-do and a lesser, poorer one
for the not-well-to-do—and for some of the latter, none.
Some will argue
that the solution is for public universities to become more efficient,
to eliminate waste, cut down bureaucracy, etc. We have been doing
that, arguably for 25 years, except where federal and state legal
requirements forced us in the other direction. And if we haven’t
yet found every possible saving, at some point we will have done
so. For most of us, cuts have already reached the core mission.
We can be leaner, but our best faculty and staff will migrate to
the less lean. It has already become, in some quarters, a recruiting
field-day for the better-off private institutions..
It is not only
that a two-tiered system of higher education based upon family wealth
is inequitable; it is also that it is not in the public interest.
By failing to provide first-quality opportunity to all our children,
we fail to mine all the talent we have. For quality of life, for
economic competitiveness, for justice and health, we need all that
talent. Those who are denied opportunity are not the only ones who
suffer: the entire society loses the benefit of their development
as members of that society.
Now, let’s
get to contingent faculty. I want to say a few things. One should
be obvious by now: I believe that the rise of contingent faculty—excepting
always those professionals who teach part-time by choice and who
bring the special value of their professional lives to the classroom—has
been neither more nor less than one outcome of the financial squeeze
on higher education.
I recognize
that not everyone here today works at a public university. But public
universities, nationwide, drive the statistics: almost 80% of students
are in public institutions, and probably a similar percentage of
faculty. And in Illinois, and some other states as well, the cutback
in state tax-based support of higher education has affected private
institutions as well, if only through the student financial aid
program.
Because contingent
faculty are not eligible for tenure, and because they participate
much less, often not at all, in university governance, their employment
in large numbers negatively affects not only their lives, but the
institutions that employ them. Joe Berry’s lead article in
the Spring 2004 issue of Illinois Academe describes these effects
in detail, and I won’t repeat them. Basically, the employment
of large numbers of contingent faculty saves money—and does
nothing else that is good, and a number of things that are bad for
students and bad for the institutions.
On the matter
of governance, however, I do want to quote Mr. Berry. He writes,
“An even more insidious impact is the collective disempowerment
of the faculty as a whole. With the majority now contingent, the
power of faculty to impact administrative decisions is greatly reduced.”
I agree with that statement, though it may make a difference to
some that I am concerned about what it says less as a matter of
faculty power per se than as a matter of good governance. That is,
I don’t think a university reaches good decisions without
a lot of strong faculty input, and even when it reaches good decisions,
it can’t implement them without preferably enthusiastic, and
at any rate willing, faculty cooperation.
But then Mr.
Berry writes two further sentences: “That is not accidental.
It is part of a conscious administrative strategy with the abolition
of tenure as a major part.” Those two sentences—and
don’t say I didn’t keep my promise to offend—are
nonsense. Unlike most of the other statements in the essay, they
are offered without any evidence, and I suspect there’s good
reason for that.
That the growth
of contingent faculty results in the weakening of tenure must be
true, at least at some undetermined tipping-point in that growth.
But that there exists some administrative strategy to destroy tenure,
either among a smaller group of unnamed administrators at unnamed
institutions, or uniformly nationwide, or in some Platonic meta-reality,
is a ridiculous and, I would submit, dangerous proposition. Let
me say why.
First, it is
useful to keep in mind that those administrators who make the critical
decisions, including the decision to hire contingent and part-time
rather than tenure-track and full-time faculty, come, at about 98%,
from faculty ranks. (I must confess: I made that number up, but
I’d bet on it.) I have always been bemused by the apparent
belief that as these people move from their full-time faculty positions
into administrative roles, a profound change in their values takes
place. People have various ideas as to which administrators make
those decisions. At the lowest level, it’s the department
head or chair. I’ve never met one who wouldn’t rather
get a tenure-line from the dean than some one-year or one-semester
cash. The same goes for the dean’s preference with regard
to the provost. And it is usually the provost who is stuck having
the balance the checkbook.
Certainly there
is pressure upon presidents and provosts to balance that checkbook.
Usually, in fact, there is no possibility of imbalance. Contingent
faculty, I would argue from what experience and knowledge I have,
is a contingent decision, forced by unpleasant circumstances. Do
the provosts and presidents want to satisfy those who require the
balanced budgets? Certainly. Can they lose their jobs if they don’t
deliver balanced budgets? Often. But is that their highest aspiration?
Rarely. How do we know what their highest aspiration is? I’d
suggest, by listening to what they brag about. They don’t
brag about their balanced budgets, and they brag about their cost-savings
only to audiences that require cost-savings as a condition of further
funding. They do brag, incessantly, about the quality of their institutions.
The quality of true higher education depends upon academic freedom,
and the safeguard for academic freedom is tenure.
You might wonder
why I am going on about this. It is because the belief that there
is a malevolent force at work here against the contingent faculty
is part of a stance that can do us yet more harm. Higher education,
and especially public higher education, is up against some formidable
forces. In various quarters we face postures of hostility bred of
political opportunism, genuine hostility, enormous competing social
needs, indifference, suspicion as to both our motives and our competence.
We face these things together. We may see ourselves in numerous
parts—faculty, staff, administration and students; or scientists,
humanists, artists and health professionals—but most of the
world sees us as monolith: universities. I’ll get back to
this point in a minute.
First, I want
to give a bit more time to the question of what we should be doing.
It has become fairly common wisdom that we in public higher education
must “privatize.” To privatize apparently means to start
acting more like private institutions, to be less dependent on state
government funding. The question is, which private institutions
should we, and could we, be more like? I would like UIC to be more
like Harvard. If you’re old-time Chicago you may recall the
moniker for Navy Pier of “Harvard on the Rocks.” I’d
like to just drop the Rocks. But I’ll compromise: we’d
only be a bit like Harvard, just the bit that would trade off our
state tax revenues for endowment income revenues. UIC has been getting
about $300 million from the state. To get endowment income of $300
million, you need an endowment of about $6 billion. Yes, philanthropy
has a role to play, but it isn’t going to replace lost state
revenues any time soon. Harvard recently announced with pride that
it would no longer charge tuition to students from families earning
less than $40,000. That’s admirable and enviable. But at UIC,
it is already the case that 34% of our undergraduates receive Pell
grants and about 35% receive Illinois MAP awards. I found myself
wondering what percent of Harvard undergraduates actually come from
families with incomes under $40,000.
We could also
privatize by raising tuition as high as the market would bear. For
our student demographic, we would also have to raise financial aid
at a somewhat faster rate than we raised tuition, if we were going
to sustain access. Or we could privatize in the sense that we could
decide that full access is someone else’s problem. Access
has been the problem—and the privilege—of the publics,
but if the publics privatize, whose will it be?
There are other
things we can do, and most we will do. We will seek more philanthropic
assistance, and invest in doing so. We will raise tuition somewhat.
We will encourage the patenting and licensing of our intellectual
property that has commercial potential, in the hope of payoffs that
can support our mission, of which advanced research is a major part.
We will pursue greater administrative efficiency, trying at the
same time not to cut the services that make our environment attractive
to faculty and students. We may even figure out how to make more
money through self-sustaining continuing education enterprises.
But at the end
of the day, I believe that if we cannot recapture the public confidence
in what we do and the public commitment to the social value of what
we do, we will not be able to sustain our mission of access to quality
education. And I also believe that we will not succeed in that recapture
if we do not act together. Against the array of circumstances and
forces threatening the very nature of our mutual enterprise, our
only hope is to stand together. We need all our collective resources.
If we are divided, we will be conquered.
And that is
why I said a few minutes ago that Mr. Berry’s hypothesis of
an adverse administrative intention is dangerous. In some dimensions,
the structure of universities puts administration and contingent
faculty in a relationship of conflict. I have $10,000 and I need
to cover two courses and so I want to hire two people at $5000.
The two people want $6000 each and probably both need and deserve
it. Now what?
I’m not
going to try to answer that, at least today. But if the answer drives
us into opposing camps, if the opposition created on this particular
issue becomes generalized, so that we no longer see ourselves as
fighting essentially on the same side of the larger issue, then
it won’t matter who wins the battle between us, because together
we will lose the enterprise itself.
We need to work
together not only to ameliorate the employment conditions of contingent
faculty and to return the large preponderance of faculty positions
to regular, tenure-track positions, but to preserve that fundamental
nature of our institutions that draws us to work for them.
Thank you for
listening.
Dr. Sylvia
Manning,
Chancellor of the University of Illinois at Chicago
_______________________
I am grateful to W. Randall Kangas, Assistant Vice President, University
of Illinois, for assistance with most of the numbers in this paper.
4/17/04 |
|